π¬ Tutorial problems iota#
Note
This problems are designed to help you practice the concepts covered in the lectures. Not all problems may be covered in the tutorial, those left are for additional practice. The symbol πΉ indicates additional problems.
\(\iota\).1#
Cobb-Douglas Preferences Specific Example:
Consider the utility function \(U(x, y)=x^{0.5} y^{0.5}\) that is defined on the consumption set \(\mathbb{R}_{+}^{2}\).
(a) Find the equation of the indifference curve that corresponds to \(U=40\).
(b) What is the slope of the indifference curve for \(U=40\) for any given value of \(x\)?
(c) What is the equation of an arbitrary indifference curve for this utility function?
(d) What is the slope of an arbitrary indifference curve for this utility function at any given value of \(x\)?
2(a)
The utility function is
The indifference curve corresponding to an amount of utility equal to 40 βutilsβ is given by the condition
Thus the equation of the indifference curve corresponding to an amount of utility equal to 40 βutilsβ is
Note that the graph of this indifference curve will be a rectangular hyperbola.
2(b)
The slope of the indifference curve corresponding to an amount of utility equal to 40 βutilsβ is given by
We can show that the marginal rate of substitution of \(x\) for \(y\) for this utility function is given by
(Exercise: Show this.) At first glance, it might appear that
in this case (when \(U=40\) ). Oh ye of little faith! Recall that the equation for the indifference curve corresponding to a utility level of forty βutilsβ was
Upon substituting this into the marginal rate of substitution expression, we obtain
so that we do indeed have
2(c)
The utility function is
The indifference curve corresponding to an arbitrary, but given, amount of utility, say \(k>0\), is given by the condition
Thus the equation of the indifference curve corresponding to a utility level of \(k>0\) is
Note that the graph of any such indifference curve (when the utility level is \(k>0\) ) will be a rectangular hyperbola.
2(d)
The slope of the indifference curve corresponding to a utility level of \(k>0\) is given by
We can show that the marginal rate of substitution of \(x\) for \(y\) for this utility function is given by
(Exercise: Show this.) At first glance, it might appear that
in this case (when \(U=k>0\) ). Oh ye of little faith! Recall that the equation for the indifference curve corresponding to a utility level of \(k>0\) was
Upon substituting this into the marginal rate of substitution expression, we obtain
so that we do indeed have
\(\iota\).2#
Marginal Rates of Substitution:
Calculate the marginal rate of substitution for an arbitrary commodity bundle of the form \((x, y)>>\) \((0,0)\) (that is, where \(x>0\) and \(y>0\) ) for each of the following utility functions.
(a) Quasi-Linear Preferences Example 1: \(U(x, y)=x+\sqrt{y}\).
(b) Quasi-Linear Preferences Example 2: \(U(x, y)=x+\ln (y)\).
(c) Stone-Geary Preferences: \(U(x, y)=\left(x-x_{0}\right)^{\alpha}\left(y-y_{0}\right)^{1-\alpha}\), where \(x_{0}>0, y_{0}>0\), and \(\alpha \in(0,1)\) are fixed parameters.
(d) Constant-Elasticity-of-Substitution (CES) Preferences: \(U(x, y)=\left(\alpha x^{\rho}+\beta y^{\rho}\right)^{\frac{1}{\rho}}\), where \(x_{0}>0, y_{0}>0\), and \(\alpha \in(0,1)\) are fixed parameters.
3(a)
The utility function is
The marginal utility of commodity \(x\) is
The marginal utility of commodity \(y\) is
The marginal rate of substitution of commodity \(x\) for commodity \(y\) is
3(b)
The utility function is
The marginal utility of commodity \(x\) is
The marginal utility of commodity \(y\) is
The marginal rate of substitution of commodity \(x\) for commodity \(y\) is
3(c)
The utility function is
The marginal utility of commodity \(x\) is
The marginal utility of commodity \(y\) is
The marginal rate of substitution of commodity \(x\) for commodity \(y\) is
3(d)
The utility function is
The marginal utility of commodity \(x\) is
The marginal utility of commodity \(y\) is
The marginal rate of substitution of commodity \(x\) for commodity \(y\) is
\(\iota\).3#
Let \(U\left(q_{1}, q_{2}\right)\) be a utility function that represents a particular individualβs preferences over bundles of strictly positive amounts of each of two commodities. Suppose that this utility function is at least twice continuously differentiable. The indifference curve corresponding to utility level \(\hat{U}\) for this individual is a graphical representation of the level-set for this utility function that corresponds to utility-level \(\hat{U}\). It is formally defined to be
The equation that describes this curve takes the form \(q_{2}=f\left(q_{1}\right)\), for some function \(f\). The function \(f\) is implicitly defined by the equation
Use the equation \(U\left(q_{1}, q_{2}\right)=\hat{U}\) to show that the slope of the above indifference curve is given by
where MRS stands for the marginal rate of substitution, and is defined to be
An indifference curve is a level-set for the utility function. Every consumption bundle on an indifference curve must generate the same level of utility. Thus the equation that describes a representative indifference curve is \(U\left(q_{1}, q_{2}\right)=k\), where \(k\) is a constant.
Along any indifference curve, utility is constant. Thus if we imagine varying \(q_{1}\) and \(q_{2}\) while stating on an indifference curve, we must have no change in the utility level \((d k=0)\).
A first-order differential approximation to the change in utility that is induced by varying \(q_{1}\) and \(q_{2}\) is given by \(d U \approx\left(\frac{\partial U}{\partial q_{1}}\right) d q_{1}+\left(\frac{\partial U}{\partial q_{2}}\right) d q_{2}=\) \(M U_{1} d q_{1}+M U_{2} d q_{2}\).
Thus at any point on an indifference curve, we must have \(M U_{1} d q_{1}+\) \(M U_{2} d q_{2} \approx 0\).
Rearranging this equation, we obtain
\(\iota\).4#
Find the degree of homogeneity, if there is one, for each of the following functions:
(a) \(f(x,y,z) = 3x+4y-3z\)
(b) \(g(x,y,z) = 3x+4y-2z-2\)
(c) \(h(x,y,z) = \frac{\sqrt{x}+\sqrt{y}+\sqrt{z}}{x+y+z}\)
(d) \(G(x,y) = \sqrt{xy} \ln \left( \frac{x^2+y^2}{xy} \right)\)
(e) \(H(x,y) = \ln x + \ln y\)
(f) \(p(x_1,\dots,x_n) = \sum_{i=1}^{n} x_i^n\)
This question comes from Sydsæter, Hammond, Strøm, and Carvajal (2016) (Section 12.7, Problem 1)
To investigate whether a function is homogenous of any degree, we can check if the condition in the definition of homogenous function is satisfied.
(a)
Hence, \(f(x,y,z)\) is homogenous of degree one
(b)
Hence, \(g(x,y,z)\) is not homogenous of any degree
(c)
Hence, \(f(x,y,z)\) is homogenous of degree \(-\frac{1}{2}\)
(d)
Hence, \(f(x,y,z)\) is homogenous of degree one
(e)
Hence, \(H(x,y)\) is not homogenous of any degree
(f)
Hence, \(f(x,y,z)\) is homogenous of degree \(n\)